top of page
  • Ivor Chipkin & Jelena Vidojevic

Monitoring and Predicting Capacity and Efficiency in Organisations

:the conceptual basis of a new methodology




Introduction

How do you know if a government department or a municipality is in a position to implement a relevant policy, or if the introduction of a new operating model is working, or if a business is able to implement the strategy that it has selected?


This paper proposes a new way of monitoring and forecasting the performance of public and private organisations. Drawing on Weber’s definition of an organisation and F.W Taylor’s notion of efficiency, we propose that the temporal regime of an organisation is an excellent proxy for efficiency and capacity. In addition, we are persuaded by Achille Mbembe’s concept of postcolonial societies as differing from others in terms of their aleatory, disruptive modes of time. We integrate this idea as a methodological intervention to focus on disruptions in the temporal regime of organisations as markers of changes in performance. We propose that this constitutes an important methodological (and technological) innovation towards a predictive model of organisational capacity and efficiency.


We discuss contemporary debates about measuring risk in organisations. We show that currently no such predictive methodology exists. We will focus, in particular, on the literature on the implementation gap, on public management, on ‘governance’ and on ‘good governance’ to show that, although they seldom ‘speak’ to each other, a synthesis is possible. We will argue that public policy necessarily presupposes an organisational configuration. In other words, it is possible to unpack or deconstruct the organisational assumptions in every policy. What we will define as policy risk – a specific category of risk – is that which describes the readiness of the organisations posited by a policy to undertake the actions necessary for its realisation.


In the second section, we will describe an approach to measuring organisational capability that combines three techniques: qualitative research, big data analytics and mathematical modelling using time-series equations.


1. Defining Risk: Towards a synthesis

Since at least the 1980s, development and policy research has sought to understand the relationship between policy intention and outcome as an organisational effect; as a consequence, that is, of the ability of organisations to plan effectively, marshal the requisite resources and deploy them effectively to the challenge at hand. In South Africa from the 1990’s much emphasis was placed on leadership in management as the key ingredient of success (Chipkin, 2011; Chipkin & Lipietz, 2012; Schwella, 2013). A similar development took place in the business environment where business strategy combined with effective leadership was often regarded as the royal road to success. This marked a shift from the approach coming from political economy that stressed, not so much organisations and how they were managed or led, but the relative power of social forces, usually class forces, whose interests were either aligned or not with specific interventions or policy goals.


Policy studies, at least since the pioneering studies by Jeffrey Pressman and Aaron Wildavsky has been preoccupied with ‘implementation’. In their authoritative study of the Economic Development Agency in the US, a project of Lyndon Johnson’s administration to promote economic development in deprived rural and later, urban areas, Pressman and Wildavsky sought to explain the gap between the project’s ambitious goals,

originally promising results and the finally disappointing outcomes (Pressman & Wildavsky, 1984).


Implementation studies has a distinctly Northern pedigree as a field that emerged in and is largely focused on organisations with already established and stable administrations. The implementation gap, that is, arises from tacit and competing imperatives and from a loss of focus arising from the introduction of multiple parties with different and competing interests. It does not arise from the instability and the weakness of administrations themselves.


Public Administration scholars tended to argue that the ‘solution’ to the implementation gap was leadership or management. There is a large scholarship today dedicated to determining how management models and styles shape performance. The task, however, is intrinsically difficult for conceptual reasons. In the first place, different organisations have different responsibilities: generating electricity, for example, or managing housing, or ensuring the delivery of school textbooks, or administering social grants. “It goes without saying”, note O’Toole and Meier, that no common measure(s) can directly tap outputs or outcomes across such diverse objectives” (O’Toole & Meier, 2011: 11). What is more, organisational goals are frequently ambiguous and vague. There is a further methodological difficulty. ‘Management’ is not a discrete activity but is a compound name for a range of actions, including scheduling, budgeting, motivating, and so on, whose definition is not fixed or given. Unsurprisingly, there is no consensus in the literature on how to theorise the relationship between management and performance (Ibid., 9).


The focus on management or leadership was, nonetheless, the optimistic end of a new scepticism about the effectiveness of organisations in the context of ‘globalisation’. The huge literature that emerged on ‘globalisation’ was accompanied by a new interest in ‘governance’, defined as the general process of establishing norms, rules and laws, of exercising power, where governments where only one element in the mix2. The ‘governance’ literature has sought to overcome some of the limits of the earlier approaches by stressing that ‘implementation gaps’, for example, are not simply the effects of weaknesses in the policy process. In an urban context, for example, many studies focus on the complex architecture of coalitions, networks and institutions (Gbaffou, 2018: 4). It is not uncommon for them to insist on the ‘ungovernability’ of situations arising from this complexity. The ability of municipalities, for example, to plan and govern cities is said to be overwhelmed by the unprecedented scale and speed of urbanization (Gbaffou, 2018: 3). Others point to the extent of urban poverty that is incommensurate with public resources (Davis, 2007) and that leads to the persistence informality and “informal people” (Chatterjee, 2004), the proliferation of “grey spaces” waiting for legalization or destruction (Yiftachel, 2009). Frequently, researchers emphasise the fluidity and instability of individual and group affiliations and belonging (Simone, 2004; Lindell, 2008), making stable urban regimes unlikely (Lipietz, 2008; Weinstein, 2008). In a related manner, various scholars focus on the recent and heterogeneous character of developing states (Bierschenck & Olivier de Sardan, 2007; Gupta, 2012), where the absence of consistent and capacitated bureaucratic organ is further undermined by rival and multiple layers of legitimacy, rights and authority (Lund, 2006). To this, authors increasingly add the recurrence of violence and the risk of political instability, and their effect on states’ ability to govern democratically (Holston, 2009; Von Holdt, 2013).


The governance literature, in emphasising the political, aleatory, fragmented and frequently violent character of decision-making (see Gbaffou, 2018, Davis, 2007, Chatterjee, 2004, Yiftachel, 2009, Lipietz, 2008, Bierschenck & Olivier de Sardan, 2007, Gupta, 2012, Holston, 2009 and Von Holdt, 2013) and social action often dissolves organisations as organised, purposeful entities. What is lost, in other words, is attention to policy intention and implementation. The ‘implementation’ literature explained policy failure in terms immanent to policymaking itself, while simultaneously simply assuming the administrative integrity of the organisations concerned. The governance literature often goes too far in the other direction. If the social is ungovernable then public policy’s focus on “giving a direction” (Peters, 1997) and on steering seems trite.


For the moment, let us note that in the aftermath of the Cold War, organisations like the World bank began stressing the relationship between ‘good governance’ and economic growth. This was an attempt to ‘bring the state back in’ (Scokpol, 1985). The concept was taken up and further developed by the international donor community and became an integral part of their engagement with transitional countries of Eastern Europe and Latin America as well as the developing countries in Africa. ‘Good governance’ became one of the key buzzwords in the development aid discourse.


“There is now widespread agreement among economists studying economic growth” wrote Rodrik, “that institutional quality holds the key to prevailing patterns of prosperity around the world” (Rodrik, 2004).


The most comprehensive indicator so far for measuring ‘good governance’ was developed by the World Bank: The Worldwide Governance Indicator Project (https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/). The project does not present one aggregated indicator of governance but covers six distinct and complex dimensions, including ‘voice and accountability’, ‘political stability’, ‘government effectiveness’, ‘regulatory policies’, ‘rule of law’ and ‘control of corruption’ (Ibid).


Peter Evans and James Rauch have nuanced this World Bank approach by arguing that the measurement of ‘government effectiveness’ should actually be a measure of what they call the ‘Weberianess’ of institutions. Evans and Rauch (1999) empirically tested the relationship between bureaucratic structure and economic growth in 35 countries. They focused on two Weberian features, meritocratic recruitment and a predictable career ladder, as measures of an organisation’s ability to deliver services (Evans & Rauch, 1999: 751). Their results suggested a very strong correlation between growth and bureaucracy. If we read these literatures (implementation, management, governance and development economics) as in debate, then it is possible to find a synthesis in their respective arguments as follows: Implementation gaps are not simply the result of weaknesses in the policy-making processes. They reflect serious challenges of governance, where organisational capabilities to control or direct action are overwhelmed by external factors. To the extent that networks, violence and other aleatory processes can be overcome in favour of organisational objectives, organisations require capable leaders and managers, together with Weberian-like administrations3.


The governance literature has or should have introduced a healthy scepticism amongst policymakers regarding the ability of organisations intentionally to produce an outcome. We do not have to believe the most extreme version of this argument – that everything is essentially ungovernable – to accept that policies rest on assumptions about implementing bodies that cannot be taken for granted. Over and above their desirability (which is a political issue), policies are reasonable to the extent that they make good or informed decisions about the organisations that must ‘do the work’4.


We might say that in South Africa after 1994, the ANC government introduced many policies that were desirable but that were not reasonable. Policymaking in South Africa is frequently done without paying due attention to the organisations that must do the work. The Reconstruction and Development Programme (RDP), for example, was jettisoned soon after its launch in favour of the Growth, Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) strategy, ostensibly on ideological grounds (see Bond, 2000; Marais, 2001), but also because the kind of coordination that the programme implied between national, provincial and local governments was unreasonable (Chipkin, 2011). There have been many other such policies. More recently in 2016, the Gauteng Department of Health cancelled a long- term contract with Life Esidimeni, a private company offering care for mentally ill patients, with a view to save money and to ‘deinstitutionalize’ psychiatric patients, in line with a new policy approach. As a result, 1 300 patients were transferred to the care of their families, non-governmental organisations (NGOs), and other hospitals, yet without adequate consideration of the NGOs in question to treat the patients that they received. 143 people died (see the arbitration report of Justice Dikgang Moseneke, 2018). In South elsewhere this failure sometimes reflects a failure to take organisations seriously, that is, to pay attention to their capabilities in the development of policies or strategies.


It also reflects a missing piece in the policy toolkit. Is it possible to know, in advance, if the organisations in question have the necessary capacities? Policymaking and planning is dependent on such knowledge. Who will design the reform of the electricity sector, for example, or an educational environment or make changes to a business practice without first estimating the capability of those charged with the task of implementation? If we return to our earlier synthesis of the literature, it is difficult to know in advance, for example, if the leadership of an organisation is sufficiently capable (qualifications and experience will only tell you so much) and/or the administration is sufficiently Weberian.


This is why the temptation to mimicry is so high. Most existing government evaluation tools end up encouraging what Matt Andrews, Lant Pritchett and Michael Woolcrock call ‘isomorphic mimicry’; the copying of the form of an organisation on the basis that is has worked elsewhere, leading to a situation where “looks like” substitutes for “does” (Andrews et al, 2017)5. Kate Bridges and Michael Woolcock noted, for example, that in 2011 half of all World Bank projects, featuring more than $50 billion, focused on institutional reform. So did those of the United Kingdom’s Department for International Development (DfID) and the Asian and African Development Banks’ portfolios (Bridges and Woolcock, p. 4). Yet in all cases the results were poor, even harmful. Why? Most of these initiatives were based on merely incorporating ‘best practice’ models and designs from around the world into local environments, but usually ignoring the particular context. Organisations and projects were regarded as successful to the extent that they conformed with ‘best practice’ models and designs that were deemed to have worked elsewhere.


The New Public Management, with its ‘management matters’ approach has been criticised for overestimating the capacity of managers to deal with governance challenges and for obscuring broader considerations of organizational capacity (Christensen & Gazley, p. 265). It also underestimated the tendency towards mimicry, conflating form for real capacity.


In summary, the tendency towards mimicry has left the fields of public policy and public administration largely without effective tools for measuring and forecasting efficiency and capacity. How can such an instrument be fashioned?


2. The Time of Organisations

Let us return briefly to the work of O’Toole and Meier, mentioned above. They define the role of managers as follows: “managers use structures, systematic processes, and procedures to regularize organizational actions. Put succinctly, organizations and their managers organize. They set up stabilizing routines that embed knowledge and experience so that cases can be handled quickly and consistently” (O’Toole & Meier, Op Cit, p. xiii). What is important about this definition of management is that it stresses the importance of regularity and stability on organisational performance. In other words, they stress the temporal dimension of capability.


This is essentially a Weberian perspective on management. Weber defined an organisation in terms of the likelihood of certain kinds of social actions being repeated over time – those approximate to an organisational role (manager, worker and so on). On his terms, organisations are a form of corporate group. They have a continuous purpose. They operate by way of applying given rules and orders, which are enforced by an administration especially established for this purpose (Weber, 1947:146).


“Corporate groups,” Weber explains, “only exist to the extent that there is a probability that certain persons will act in such a way as to tend to carry out the order governing the group” (our emphasis) (Ibid., p. 146). If there is no probability of this type of action on the part of a particular group of persons, that is, the actions to enforce the rules or orders given by a chief or leader or manager, there is only a social relationship but no corporate group (Ibid., p.147). Weber emphasises this relational and probabilistic character of organisations over and over again. A ‘state’, for example, ceases to exist in a sociologically relevant sense whenever there is no longer a probability that certain kinds of meaningfully oriented social action will take place (Ibid, p.118). That is, ‘Kings’, ‘bureaucrats’, ‘subjects’, ‘citizens’, ‘presidents’ do not come into meaningful existence unless the social actors occupying those positions act in ways approximate to the roles of ‘Kings’ etc6. We could add, ‘directors’, ‘managers’, ‘workers’ and so on.


The relationship or distance between social action and formal, organisational roles is an area ripe for study, though it does not always receive the treatment it deserves in the field of public administration. One of the important exceptions, in this regard, is Michael Lipsky’s ‘Street-level bureaucracy’. There Lipsky considered the difficulty for frontline service providers of performing their roles in the absence of the time, information and resources needed to do so optimally (Lipsky, 2010).When an official deviates from a rule or a norm political scientists and sociologists frequently explain such behaviour in terms of neopatrimonialism (Crawford Young, 1994), self-interest and corruption, including ‘state capture’ (Hellman et al, 2000), political interference (Chipkin, 2012; Chipkin & Swilling et al, 2018). In anthropology, Trouillot notes that sociocultural anthropologists have not given these questions the attention they deserve (Trouillot, 2001: 126). This is beginning to change, albeit slowly. The important exception to this rule is in the field of what has come to be known as behavioural economics, where researchers consider ways of helping to ‘nudge’ consumers and citizens to behave ‘reasonably’ (see Kahneman, 2011; Thaler, 2015). Behavioural economics has started to influence the policy space in some countries. How to close the gap between an actor’s formal role and designation in an organisation and their actual conduct remains one of the key theoretical challenges for research and the foremost practical challenge for organisations.


Probability is the likelihood of an event or action taking place in the future. It is in other words, a temporal relation. Hence, closing the gap between an individual’s formal designation in an organisation and what they actually do in the workplace is about reconciling over time their de facto conduct and their necessary conduct. Strangely, this key dimension of performance is often overlooked, especially in corporations where the tendency amongst Human Resources officers is to consider the gap as a function of skill and personality (hence the strange appeal today Enneagrams). Christen and Gazley note in their extensive review of the public administration and policy literature, however, that ‘time’ as a variable in the study of performance has hardly been considered. They write: “the dimension of time is the principal element missing from current frameworks in public and non-profit management” (Christensen & Gazley, Op Cit., p. 276).


3. The Temporal Regime

F.W. Taylor’s ‘scientific revolution’ in the management of organisations marked nothing less than a temporal revolution in the running of companies. The move to greater efficiency, in individual businesses and in the national economy, would be achieved through a double movement. In the first place, it required overcoming (old) systems of management where the “imperative [is] that each workman shall be left with the final responsibility for doing his job practically as he thinks best” (Taylor, p. 25). In the second, the remedy for inefficiency lay in “systematic management”, a “true science”, resting on the application of “clearly defined laws, rules and principles (Ibid, p.7).


“The enormous saving of time,” Taylor enthused, “and, therefore, increase in the output which it is possible to effect through eliminating unnecessary motions and substituting fast for slow and inefficient motions for the men working in any of our trades can be fully realized only after one has personally seen the improvement which results from a thorough motion and time study” (Ibid., p.24) (emphasis added). In any work routine, Taylor continued, where there are potentially dozens and dozens of ways of working, “there is always one method and one implement which is quicker and better than the rest”. “And this one best method and best implement can only be discovered or developed through a scientific study and analysis of all the methods and implements in use, together with accurate, minute, motion and time study” (Ibid., p. 25).


Efficiency, that is, was to be achieved by finding the best way of performing specific tasks as quickly as possible according to the careful study of how best to move the worker’s body, place their arms, their legs, their head and so on in relation to the machine, tools and/or instruments designed for the task at hand.

So far-reaching was the impact of Taylorist conceptions that his work is widely deemed responsible for the lineaments of the modern factory system in the US, in Britain and in France (Littler, 1978: 200), for the organisation of Soviet industry from the 1920s (Sochor, 1981) and as the basis of Japanese industrial production after the Second World War (Tsutsui, 1998). Even the movement that developed in the 1930s in opposition to Taylorist practices – Human Resources Management, for example – was not so much an anti-Taylorist movement as a form of Neo-Taylorism (de Montmollin & Tombelaine, 1975: 13). It rejected Taylor’s particular view on workers autonomy, tendency towards laziness and so on, but retained the rationalist sensibility that the work process should be subjected to a strict discipline of time and motion.


Taylor’s focus was on improving efficiency by modelling human actions and crafting instruments/ tools to best achieve specific tasks. In the 1930s, concern to increase productivity in American firms saw experimental research done on motivation. Studies by Elton Mayo, for example, found that output improved in situations where workers experienced recognition in the workplace (Grey, 2009: 45). Efficiency was not simply a technical relation between the body, the tool and the task, that is. It was also a social relation, determined by the quality of teamwork, by the level of cooperation between managers and workers, by the extent and type of internal communications and, generally, on the quality of work-based relationships. Drucker famously insisted that management was about making human beings “capable of joint performance” and was, therefore, “deeply embedded in culture” (Drucker, 2001) – the basis of the famous, probably apocryphal rejoinder to Porter that ‘culture eats strategy for breakfast’. Today Human Resource Management (HRM) is said to operate through a system that includes HR philosophies, strategies, policies, processes, practices and programmes (Armstrong, 2006: 4). The purpose of HRM is always, nonetheless, “the close integration of human resources policies with business strategy“ so that “employees as a resource [are] managed in the same rational way as any other resource being exploited for maximum return” (Legge cited in Armstrong, 2006: 12).


Like Taylorism, Human Resource Management is a way of disciplining staff according to time. Whereas Taylor emphasised the individual worker in relation to a task, Human Resources Management scholars emphasise the team in relation to projects. Central to the definition of a project, however, is a measure of time. James and Albert (1994), for

example, define a project as an item of work requiring planning, organizing and resources and funds. Harold (2003) makes the temporal dimension of planning more explicit by defining a project as any series of activities and tasks that have a specific objective to be completed within a certain timeframe. Dhillon, (2002), does similarly when he calls project management the art of directing and coordinating material and human resources through the project life span to achieve predetermined goals.


We can summarise the discussion so far as follows:

From the perspective of ‘efficiency’, the temporal structure of an organisation is the aggregate time that it takes to perform specific tasks or clusters of tasks in relation to organisational outputs.


From the perspective of ‘capacity’, the temporal structure of an organisation is a measure of the likelihood or probability that an individual will conduct themselves according to what is needed to be a ‘manager’, ‘HR officer’, ‘worker’ and so on. It is what the philosophers (following Foucault) might call a relation of subjection. Corruption as the ‘abuse of public office for private gain’ is a term that describes the misalignment between the formal role and what the person occupying it actually does with their time. Taken together, capacity and efficiency are both relations in time that can be measured by modelling an organisation’s temporal structure. We believe that this insight constitutes an important contribution both to the theoretical and practical knowledge of modelling and forecasting risk in organisations. The second theoretical contribution that this paper makes is how to measure such a temporal regime. Let us return to the idea of postcoloniality, which we left hanging earlier.


Disturbances in Time

Achille Mbembe, the South African based philosopher has, in conversation with the anthropologist Jean Comaroff, proposed that the key intellectual challenge in the study of African societies is to “write the world from Africa or write Africa into contemporary social theory” (Weaver Shipley, Comaroff & Mbembe, 2010: 658). At stake in the question is a theoretical and methodological problem.

The best starting point for writing Africa, Mbembe suggested, was to analyse the “structures of temporality” in colonial and postcolonial conditions as a way of uncovering the rules, regularities and reproductive logics that underpin the current conditions (Ibid.,p. 658). Mbembe defines the structure of the postcolonial condition in terms of the contingent, the ephemeral, the fugitive and fortuitous, as a condition of “radical uncertainty and social volatility”. This is what he defines as a state of temporariness. Temporariness is characterised by “life changing rapidly”. It also describes a domain of life that is “hardly the object of documentation, archiving, or empirical description” (Ibid., p.661). Temporariness is not simply a social condition. It is an organisational one too. Temporal structures – speed, acceleration, form – provide a privileged perspective from which to observe and analyse social and organisation life in postcolonial conditions. Yet the postcolonial is also a description of a state of change or transition from the colonial into what we do not yet know, or we know only in the softest of shadows. As such, it marks a period of transition. Theoretically, the study of temporal structures, is a preeminent methodology for the analysis of transitional societies and/or organisations in transition.


Postcolonial societies, like others in political transition, are marked by multiple temporalities, where the organisation is not able to impose either the time of the task or the time of the project on staff members. Put differently, organisations in transitional societies tend towards inefficiency and incapacity depending on the degree to which staff (managers, workers and so on) perform their jobs according to the temporal structure of the task or the project or whether they are motivated by other commitments; to family and kin (neopatrimonialism), to religious bodies (theological time), friendships (affect) and so on.


From this perspective, the temporal structure of organisations in postcolonial or transitional environments is likely to be marked by discontinuities in the time series or disruptions. Disruptions in the organisation are likely to reduce efficiency because the tendency of social actors:


- to comply with their organisational roles will be affected, as either the people change and/or the roles are redefined and renamed, sometimes capriciously.

- to work timeously and correctly will compromised for the same reasons.

Organisational efficiency and capacity, that is, can be measured negatively by modelling the number and duration of disruptions. To the best of our knowledge we are the first to propose evaluating the efficiency of organisations in this way.


In summary we argue that organisations as such are measures of probability that staff will perform their tasks as ‘workers’, ‘managers’, ‘engineers’, ‘support staff’ and so on. This is a relation of subjection, of, that is, being subjected to a role. Secondly, Subjection to a role can best be analysed through a study of the temporal structures of a task or a project team. Efficiency in an organisation occurs when tasks are completed in the most regular and speedy fashion. In transitional societies, however, temporal structure in organisations are usually given by their ‘temporariness’, defined as a condition of uncertainty and volatility. This explains why tasks in organisations in such environments frequently fail to perform adequately.


Conclusion

This paper has sought to contribute to both theoretical and practical debates in the field of policymaking. Since the 1990s scholars working from the perspective of ‘governance’ or the related field of postcolonial studies have raised important theoretical objections to policy studies, even if only implicitly. That is, they have cast doubts on the possibility of organisations working purposefully in the context of fluid and elusive social networks, violence, poverty and so on. To the extent that public administration scholars have addressed this critique they have stressed the importance of management in organisations and the role of managers in overcoming these governance challenges to achieve organisational goals. Development Economists have further stressed the importance of ‘good governance’ generally and the importance of rule-bound and meritocratic administrations. In other words, public administration and management scholars as well as development scholars have suggested that there are ways of overcoming the general tendency towards ungovernability. The problem is that there is currently no way of knowing or predicting when this is the case. Merely reproducing models or processes that have worked elsewhere (isomorphic mimicry) is a sure route to frustration. Hence, policymaking largely operates in the dark.


This paper has proposed a solution to this problem. We have discussed the basis of a new methodology for monitoring and predicting organisational performance, whether in a government department, an agency, a state-owned enterprise or a private business, by modelling what we have called their temporal regimes.


We have seen that terms like ‘efficiency’ and ‘capacity’ are temporal concepts that either measure certain actions over time or that measure the probability of actions happening in time. Modelling these relations and probabilities gives an accurate measure and forecast of an organisation’s performance over time. We have drawn from postcolonial theory, moreover, to suggest that a good way of determining such a temporal regime is by modelling disruptions. This approach lends itself to mathematical modelling, using time- series equations


We believe that the approach developed here is a first for accurately modelling the efficiency or capacity of an organisation using Big Data and AI techniques, instead of traditional qualitative methodologies. The methodology (and associated technology) outlined in this paper will allow policy-makers, corporate heads and managers to test the reasonableness of their organisational assumptions quickly and at scale. In this way, we have proposed a technique to bring greater light to the policy-making process.


References

Andrews, M & Pritchett, L & Woolcock, M, 2017. Building State Capability: Evidence, Analysis, Action. Oxford University Press, Oxford.


Armstrong, M, 2006. A Handbook of Human Resource Management. 10th edn. Kogan Page, London & Philadelphia.

Bénit-Gbaffou, C, 2018. Beyond the Policy-Implementation Gap: How the City of Johannesburg Manufactured the Ungovernability of Street Trading. The Journal of Development Studies, 54(12), 2149-2167.


Bierschenk, T & Olivier de Sardan, J.-P. (Eds.). 2007. States at work: Dynamics of African bureaucracies. Brill, Leiden.


Bond, P, 2000. Elite Transition: From Apartheid to Neoliberalism in South Africa. Pluto Press, London and Sterling, Virginia & University of Natal Press, Pietermaritzburg.


Bridges, Kate & Woolcock, Michael. December 2017. How (Not) to Fix Problems That Matter: Assessing and Responding to Malawi’s History of Institutional Reform. Policy Research Working Paper 8289. The World Bank Group, Washington.


Chatterjee, P, 2004. The politics of the governed: Reflections on popular politics in most of the world. Columbia University Press, New York.


Chipkin, I & Lipietz, B, 2012. Transforming South Africa’s Racial Bureaucracy: New Public Management and public sector reform in contemporary South Africa. Wits Institute for Social and Economic Research, Johannesburg. https://wiser.wits.ac.za/content/transforming-south-africa’s-racial-bureaucracy-new- public-management-and-public-sector (accessed 12 April, 2020).


Chipkin, I, 2011. Transcending bureaucracy: state transformation in the age of the manager. Transformation: Critical Perspectives on Southern Africa, 77, 31-51.


Christensen, R. K & Gazley, B, 2008. Capacity for Public Administration: Analysis of Meaning and Measurement. Public Administration and Development, 28, 265-279.


Cox, K & Jolly, S & Van Der Staaij, S & Van Stolk, C, 2018. Understanding the Drivers of Organisational Capacity. The Rand and Saatchi Institute, Santa Monica, California & Cambridge, UK.

Craig R. L, 1978. Understanding Taylorism. The British Journal of Sociology, 29(2), 185-202.


Davis, M, 2007. Planet of slums. Verso, London.


De Montmollin, M & Tombelaine, V, 1975. Taylorism and Anti-Taylorism. International Studies of Management & Organization, 5(3), 4-15.


Drucker, P, 2001. The Essential Drucker. Management Challenges in the 21st Century. Harper Collins.


Evans, P & Rauch, J. E, 1999. Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Effects of “Weberian” State Structures on Economic Growth. American Sociological Review, 64 (5), 748-765.


Gupta, A, 2012. Red tape: Bureaucracy, structural violence, and poverty in India. Duke University Press, Durham, NC.


Graduate School of Development Policy and Practice, 2013, Why the Lights Went Out. Reform in the South African Energy Sector, a report produced by the Public Affairs Research Institute (PARI) for the University of Cape Town.


Hellman, J, Jones, G, Kaufman, D & Schankerman, M, 2000. Measuring Governance, Corruption and State Capture: How Firms and Bureaucrats Shape the Business Environment in Transitional Economies, World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 2312, Washington.


Holston, J, 2009. Insurgent citizenship: Disjuncture between democracy and modernity. Princeton University Press, Princeton.


Huynh-Quan-Suu, C. Étymologie du terme ‘gouvernance’, https://ec.europa.eu/governance/docs/doc5_fr.pdf (accessed 01/01/2020) Innovations for Successful Societies, available at: https://successfulsocieties.princeton.edu


Justice Dikgang M. March 19th, 2018. Families of Mental Health Care Users Affected by the Gauteng Mental Marathon Project v. National Minister of Health of the Republic of South Africa and Others, arbitration award.


Kahneman, D, 2012. Thinking Fast and Slow. Penguin Books, London.


Levy, B, Cameron, R, Hoadley, U & Naidoo, V, 2016. The Politics and Governance of Basic Education. A Tale of Two South African Provinces. ESID Working Paper No. 67. Manchester, UK: The University of Manchester. Available at: www.effective- states.org (accessed 12 May 2020)


Lindell, I, 2008. The multiple sites of urban governance: Insights from an African city. Urban Studies, 45(9), 1879–1901.


Lipietz, B, 2004. ‘Muddling-through’: Urban regeneration in Johannesburg’s inner city. Paper presented to the N-AERUS annual conference. Barcelona. Spain.


Lipsky, M, 2010. Street-level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the individual in public services. Russel Sage Foundation, New York.

Lund, C, 2006. Twilight institutions: Public authority and local politics in Africa. Development and Change, 37, 685–705.


Marais, H, 2001. South Africa: Limits to Change. The Political Economy of Transition. Zed Books, New York.


Montgomery, D.C., Jennings, C. and Kulahci, M, 2008, Introduction to Time Series Analysis and Forecasting, New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons.


O’Toole, L. J. Jr & Meier, K. J, 2011. Public Management: Organisations, Governance and Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.


Peters, B. G, 1997. Shouldn’t row, can’t steer: What’s a government to do? Public Policy and Administration, 12(2), 51–61.


Porter, Michael E, 1998. Competitive Strategy. Techniques for Analysing Industries and Competitors. The Free Press, New York.


Pressman, J. L & Wildavsky, A, 1984. Implementation. How Great Expectations in Washington Are Dashed in Oakland; Or, Why It’s Amazing that Federal Programs Work at All, This Being a Saga of the Economic Development Administration as Told by Two Sympathetic Observers Who Seek to Build Morals on a Foundation. University of California Press.


Rodrik, D, 2004. Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century. KSG Faculty Research Working Papers Series.


Sanderson, I, 2001. Evaluation, Policy Learning and Evidence-Based Policy Making. Public Administration, 80(1),1–22.


Schwella, E, 2013. Bad Public Leadership in South Africa: the Jackie Selebi Case. Scientia Militaria, South African Journal of Military Studies, 41(1), 65-90.


Simone, A, 2004. People as infrastructure: Intersecting fragments in Johannesburg. Public Culture, 16, 407–429.


Skocpol, T, 1985. Bringing the State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in Current Research. In: Evans, P. Rueschemeyer, D. & Skocpol, T. (eds.). Bringing the State Back In. 3-38. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.


Smith, A. F. M. Public policy issues as a route to statistical awareness, http://www.tilastokeskus.fi/isi99/proceedings/arkisto/varasto/smit0993.pdf (accessed 29 December 2019).


Taylor, F. W, 2003. Scientific Management. Routledge, Abingdon, Oxon.


Thales, R. H, 2015. Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioural Economics. W. W. Norton & Company, New York & London:


Trouillot, M.R, 2001. The Anthropology of the State in the Age of Globalisation: Close Encounters of the Deceptive Kind. Current Anthropology, 42(1), 125-138.


Tsutsui, M. W, 1998. Manufacturing Ideology: Scientific Management in Twentieth Century Japan. Princeton University Press, Princeton.


Von Holdt, K, 2013. South Africa: The transition to violent democracy. Review of African Political Economy, 40, 589–604.


Weaver, S, Comaroff, J & Mbembe, A, 2010. Africa in Theory: A Conversation Between Jean Comaroff and Achille Mbembe. Anthropological Quarterly, 83(3). 653-678.


Weber, M, 1947. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. The Free Press, NY & London: Collier-Macmillan Limited.


Weinstein, L, 2008. Mumbai’s development mafias: Globalization, organized crime and land development. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 32, 22– 39.


Worldwide Governance Indicators, available at: https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/ (accessed 12 May 2020)


Yiftachel, O, 2009. Critical theory and ‘grey space’. Mobilization of the colonized. City, 13, 240–256.


2 views
bottom of page